Thailand: A Casualty of the Asian Financial Crisis

Advertisements

In the narrative of modern economic development in Asia, Japan emerged as a pivotal player with grand ambitions of dominating the regional economyThis ambition unfolded primarily through a distinctive economic model that highlighted Japan's role as the leader in East Asia's economic landscape.

During the 1970s and 1980s, Japan experienced an astonishing surge in its economy, catapulting itself to the position of the world's second-largest economyThis growth period spanned over three decades following World War II, a time when Japan's Gross Domestic Product (GDP) outstripped that of all other Asian nations combined, and its financial assets were roughly twice that totalThis was a time of unparalleled prosperity and economic prowess for Japan, signaling a golden era.

Post economic ascendance, Japan embarked on a path of expansion throughout Asia, playing a catalytic role through what is known as the "East Asian Flying Geese Model." This model had profound implications for the economic dynamics of the East Asian region.

The concept of the "Flying Geese Model" positions Japan as the leading goose that directs high-technology, high-profit industriesAs Japan's industries evolved and labor costs escalated, Japanese businesses began relocating outdated, less efficient production capabilities to the lesser-developed economies of the "Asian Tigers"—comprising South Korea, Taiwan, Hong Kong, and SingaporeThis model relied on a cascading effect, where Japanese firms moved to lower-cost countries, which in turn transferred industries to even less-developed nations in the next tier, referred to as the "Asian Little Tigers."

During this arrangement, Japan's role was to provide vital technology, equipment, and capital, while the receiving nations opened their markets and supplied inexpensive labor and resourcesA critical backdrop to this economic shift was the Cold War period—where the intense rivalry between the United States and the Soviet Union created economic environments that often hinged on cooperation and dependence

Advertisements

Meanwhile, China's engagement in global trade was still marginal, preventing a unified regional identity within the supply chains at that time.

Considering the structural inequities, the East Asian model ostensibly appeared to promise collective wealth, where Japan would lead by example to propel neighboring economiesHowever, lurking beneath this polished veneer was a complex web of exploitation; Japan's dominance in technology enabled it to retain control over the high-profit sectors of the supply chain, effectively consigning its "flying geese" to low-margin, labor-intensive industries that often had detrimental environmental implications.

As the primary goose, Japan thrived on the disparity, and its ability to dictate terms for investment, technology, and developmental strategies further entrenched the dependency of its counterparts on Japanese economic assistance.

The architectural design of the Flying Geese Model bears striking resemblance to the "Core-Periphery Model" pioneered by the United States post-World War IIThe U.S. capitalized on its prowess across military, technological, and financial domains to establish itself as the leading goose globally, with the G7 nations composing a secondary layer, while various other nations populated the broader peripheryJapan's ambition was to replicate this successful model in East Asia.

Despite Japan's meticulous planning, the dream of establishing its economic preeminence in East Asia came shattering down during the 1998 Asian Financial CrisisThe catalyst of this turmoil was rooted in events from 1985—the signing of the Plaza Accord among Japan, the United States, the United Kingdom, France, and Germany, which set the stage for dramatic shifts in currency valuation.

This agreement initiated a decade-long appreciation of the yen, soaring from 250 yen per dollar in 1985 to an astonishing 80 yen per dollar by 1995—an increase of 300%. The immediate impact of this currency shift rippled across East Asia, unwittingly giving rise to economic booms in neighboring countries.

Examining the scenario in Thailand, for instance, it adopted a fixed exchange rate tethered to the U.S. dollar just prior to the Plaza Accord

Advertisements

As the dollar depreciated, the Thai baht followed suit, significantly bolstering the export competitiveness of Thai productsDuring the yen's high-rise decade, Thai economic metrics like exports surged, leading to substantial trade surpluses and significant Japanese investment influx, contributing to an extraordinary growth trajectory that boasted rates above 8% per annum.

Yet, this exuberance masked an underlying crisisThe United States consistently imposed economic pressures against JapanBy 1995, the economic tides dramatically shifted: with the advent of President Clinton in 1992, benefitting from the collapse of the Soviet Union and the tech revolution, the U.S. economy entered a growth phase.

In February 1994, as the Federal Reserve commenced an interest rate hike cycle to stave off economic overheating, Japan found itself reeling from a stagnating economy rooted in the aftermath of the 1991 asset bubble burstInitial tactics to stimulate growth involved steep interest rates reductions, causing a disparity between U.S. and Japanese rates that reached an unprecedented 4.5%. These dynamics set the stage for a reversal in economic fates from 1995 onwards.

As the dollar regained strength and the yen faltered, the repercussions were felt harshly by East Asian economies, particularly Thailand which had relied heavily on the previous yen-dollar dynamicsFollowing an unrelenting downturn beginning in April 1995, Thailand was confronted with crushing competition from China and other global economic forces.

With rising U.S. dollar valuations, Thai exports plummeted, while regional trade agreements in North America and the European Union hampered Thailand’s ability to compete for marketsCompounding this were the pressures from China that dramatically devalued the renminbi, further squeezing Thailand's market share.

In addition, it was a turbulent time for Japanese investorsAfter the 1991 economic bubble burst, Japanese banks faced mounting non-performing loans

Advertisements

The devastating Kobe earthquake in 1995 inflicted additional financial strains, leading many Japanese firms to withdraw investments from Thailand at alarming rates.

In a bid to comply with international regulatory requirements, Japanese banks began retracting loans from Southeast AsiaBetween 1995 and 1999, approximately $192.5 billion was receded from the Southeast Asian market, with Thailand bearing the brunt of the financial fallout.

As the situation grew increasingly dire, Thailand faced ballooning trade deficits and a severe capital outflow crisis, with the pressure to depreciate the baht soaringHowever, the government, caught in the dilemma of maintaining a fixed exchange rate tethered to the dollar and loaded with crippling debts, could not afford to let the currency falter.

To stabilize its failing economy, Thailand attempted to attract capital inflow by opening its marketsHowever, the volatile nature of this financial capital posed a substantial risk, often resulting in abrupt capital flightThis precarious situation became the substrate for the 1998 Asian Financial Crisis, upending the economic illusion created by Japan’s Flying Geese Model and leading to a profound transformation in Asia's economic landscape.

Write A Review

Etiam tristique venenatis metus,eget maximus elit mattis et. Suspendisse felis odio,

Please Enter Your 5 star Reviews*